Thursday, July 23, 2015
Tuesday, July 21, 2015
Democracy Rising World Conference 2015, LIVESTREAM
http://therealnews.com/t2/index.php?option=com_content&task=view&id=2465
Friday, July 17, 2015
Yanis Varoufakis, Dr Schäuble’s Plan for Europe: Do Europeans approve?
http://yanisvaroufakis.eu/2015/07/17/dr-schaubles-plan-for-europe-do-europeans-approve-english-version-of-my-article-in-die-zeit/
Dr Schäuble’s Plan for the
Eurozone
The avalanche of toxic
bailouts that followed the Eurozone’s first financial crisis offers ample proof
that the non-credible ‘no bailout clause’ was a terrible substitute for
political union. Wolfgang Schäuble knows this and has made clear his plan to
forge a closer union. “Ideally, Europe would be a political union”, he wrote in
a joint article with Karl Lamers, the CDU’s former foreign affairs chief (Financial
Times, 1st September 2014).
Dr Schäuble is right to
advocate institutional changes that might provide the Eurozone with its missing
political mechanisms. Not only because it is impossible otherwise to address
the Eurozone’s current crisis but also for the purpose of preparing our
monetary union for the next crisis. The question is: Is his specific plan a
good one? Is it one that Europeans should want? How do its authors propose that
it be implemented?
The Schäuble-Lamers Plan rests
on two ideas: “Why not have a European budget commissioner” asked Schäuble and
Lamers “with powers to reject national budgets if they do not correspond to the
rules we jointly agreed?” “We also favour”, they added “a ‘Eurozone parliament’
comprising the MEPs of Eurozone countries to strengthen the democratic
legitimacy of decisions affecting the single currency bloc.”
The first point to raise about
the Schäuble-Lamers Plan is that it is at odds with any notion of democratic
federalism. A federal democracy, like Germany, the United States or Australia,
is founded on the sovereignty of its citizens as reflected in the positive
power of their representatives to legislate what must be done on the sovereign
people’s behalf.
In sharp contrast, the
Schäuble-Lamers Plan envisages only negative powers: A Eurozonal budget
overlord (possibly a glorified version of the Eurogroup’s President) equipped
solely with negative, or veto, powers over national Parliaments. The problem
with this is twofold. First, it would not help sufficiently to safeguard the
Eurozone’s macro-economy. Secondly, it would violate basic principles of
Western liberal democracy.
Consider events both prior to
the eruption of the euro crisis, in 2010, and afterwards. Before the crisis,
had Dr Schäuble’s fiscal overlord existed, she or he might have been able to
veto the Greek government’s profligacy but would be in no position to do
anything regarding the tsunami of loans flowing from the private banks of
Frankfurt and Paris to the Periphery’s private banks.[2] Those capital outflows underpinned unsustainable
debt that, unavoidably, got transferred back onto the public’s shoulders the
moment financial markets imploded. Post-crisis, Dr Schäuble’s budget Leviathan
would also be powerless, in the face of potential insolvency of several states
caused by their bailing out (directly or indirectly) the private banks.
In short, the new high office
envisioned by the Schäuble-Lamers Plan would have been impotent to prevent the
causes of the crisis and to deal with its repercussions. Moreover, every time
it did act, by vetoing a national budget, the new high office would be
annulling the sovereignty of a European people without having replaced it by a
higher-order sovereignty at a federal or supra-national level.
Dr Schäuble has been
impressively consistent in his espousal of a political union that runs contrary
to the basic principles of a democratic federation. In an article in Die Welt
published on 15th June 1995, he dismissed the “academic debate” over
whether Europe should be “…a federation or an alliance of states”. Was he right
that there is no difference between a federation and an ‘alliance of states’? I
submit that a failure to distinguish between the two constitutes a major threat
to European democracy.
Forgotten prerequisites for a
liberal democratic, multinational political union
One often forgotten fact about
liberal democracies is that the legitimacy of its laws and constitution is
determined not by its legal content but by politics. To claim, as Dr Schäuble
did in 1995, and implied again in 2014, that it makes no difference whether the
Eurozone is an alliance of sovereign states or a federal state is purposely to
ignore that the latter can create political authority whereas the
former cannot.
An ‘alliance of states’ can,
of course, come to mutually beneficial arrangements against a common aggressor
(e.g. in the context of a defensive military alliance), or in agreeing to
common industry standards, or even effect a free trade zone. But, such an
alliance of sovereign states can never legitimately create an overlord with the
right to strike down a states’ sovereignty, since there is no collective,
alliance-wide sovereignty from which to draw the necessary political authority
to do so.
This is why the difference
between a federation and an ‘alliance of states’ matters hugely. For while a
federation replaces the sovereignty forfeited at the national or state level
with a new-fangled sovereignty at the unitary, federal level, centralising
power within an ‘alliance of states’ is, by definition, illegitimate, and lacks
any sovereign body politic that can anoint it. Nor can any Euro Chamber of the
European Parliament, itself lacking the power to legislate at will, legitimise
the Budget Commissioner’s veto power over national Parliaments.
To put it slightly differently,
small sovereign nations, e.g. Iceland, have choices to make within the broader
constraints created for them by nature and by the rest of humanity. However
limited these choices, Iceland’s body politic retains absolute authority
to hold their elected officials accountable for the decisions they have reached
within the nation’s exogenous constraints and to strike down every piece of
legislation that it has decided upon in the past. In juxtaposition, the
Eurozone’s finance ministers often return from Eurogroup meetings decrying the
decisions that they have just signed up to, using the standard excuse that “it
was the best we could negotiate within the Eurogroup”.
The euro crisis has expanded
this lacuna at the centre of Europe hideously. An informal body, the Eurogroup,
that keeps no minutes, abides by no written rules, and is answerable to
precisely no one, is running the world’s largest macro-economy, with a Central
Bank struggling to stay within vague rules that it creates as it goes along,
and no body politic to provide the necessary bedrock of political legitimacy on
which fiscal and monetary decisions may rest.
Will Dr Schäuble’s Plan remedy
this indefensible system of governance? If anything, it would dress up the
Eurogroup’s present ineffective macro-governance and political authoritarianism
in a cloak of pseudo-legitimacy. The malignancies of the present ‘Alliance of
States’ would be cast in stone and the dream of a democratic European
federation would be pushed further into an uncertain future.
Dr Schäuble’s perilous
strategy for implementing the Schäuble-Lamers Plan
Back in May, in the sidelines of yet another Eurogroup meeting, I had had the privilege of a fascinating conversation with Dr Schäuble. We talked extensively both about Greece and regarding the future of the Eurozone. Later on that day, the Eurogroup meeting’s agenda included an item on future institutional changes to bolster the Eurozone. In that conversation, it was abundantly clear that Dr Schäuble’s Plan was the axis around which the majority of finance ministers were revolving.
Though Grexit was not referred
to directly in that Eurogroup meeting of nineteen ministers, plus the
institutions’ leaders, veiled references were most certainly made to it. I
heard a colleague say that member-states that cannot meet their commitments
should not count on the Eurozone’s indivisibility, since reinforced discipline
was of the essence. Some mentioned the importance of bestowing upon a permanent
Eurogroup President the power to veto national budgets. Others discussed the
need to convene a Euro Chamber of Parliamentarians to legitimise her or his
authority. Echoes of Dr Schäuble’s Plan reverberated throughout the room.
Judging from that Eurogroup
conversation, and from my discussions with Germany’s Finance Minister, Grexit
features in Dr Schäuble’s Plan as a crucial move that would kickstart the
process of its implementation. A controlled escalation of the long suffering
Greeks’ pains, intensified by shut banks while ameliorated by some humanitarian
aid, was foreshadowed as the harbinger of the New Eurozone. On the one hand,
the fate of the prodigal Greeks would act as a morality tale for governments
toying with the idea of challenging the existing ‘rules’ (e.g. Italy), or of
resisting the transfer of national sovereignty over budgets to the Eurogroup
(e.g. France). On the other hand, the prospect of (limited) fiscal transfers
(e.g. a closer banking union and a common unemployment benefit pool) would
offer the requisite carrot (that smaller nations craved).
Setting aside any moral or
philosophical objections to the idea of forging a better union through
controlled boosts in the suffering of a constituent member-state, several
broader questions pose themselves urgently:
Are the means fit for the
ends?
Is the abrogation of the
Eurozone’s constitutional indivisibility a safe means of securing its future as
a realm of shared prosperity?
Will the ritual sacrifice of a
member-state help bring Europeans closer together?
Does the argument that
elections cannot change anything in indebted member-states inspire trust in
Europe’s institutions?
Or might it have the precise
opposite effect, as fear and loathing become established parts of Europe’s
intercourse?
Conclusion: Europe at a crossroads
The Eurozone’s faulty
foundations revealed themselves first in Greece, before the crisis spread
elsewhere. Five years later, Greece is again in the limelight as Germany’s sole
surviving statesman from the era that forged the euro, Dr Wolfgang Schäuble,
has a plan to refurbish Europe’s monetary union that involves jettisoning
Greece on the excuse that the Greek government has no ‘credible’ reforms on
offer.
The reality is that a
Eurogroup sold to Dr Schäuble’s Plan, and strategy, never had any serious
intention to strike a New Deal with Greece reflecting the common interests of
creditors and of a nation whose income had been crushed, and whose society was
fragmented, as a result of a terribly designed ‘Program’. Official Europe’s
insistence that this failed ‘Program’ be adopted by our new government ‘or
else’ was nothing but the trigger for the implementation of Dr Schäuble’s Plan.
It is quite telling that, the
moment negotiations collapsed, our government’s argument that Greece’s debt had
to be restructured as part of any viable agreement was, belatedly,
acknowledged. The International Monetary Fund was the first institution to do
so. Remarkably Dr Schäuble himself also acknowledged that debt relief was
needed but hastened to add that it was politically “impossible”. What I am sure
he really meant was that it was undesirable, to him, because his aim is to
justify a Grexit that triggers the implementation of his Plan for Europe.
Perhaps it is true that, as a
Greek and a protagonist in the past five months of negotiations, my assessment
of the Schäuble-Lamers Plan, and of their chosen means, is too biased to matter
in Germany.
Germany has been a loyal
European ‘citizen’ and the German people, to their credit, have always yearned
to embed their nation-state, to lose themselves in an important sense, within a
united Europe. So, setting aside my views on the matter, the question is this:
What do you, dear reader,
think of it? Is Dr Schäuble’s Plan consistent with your dream of a democratic
Europe? Or will its implementation, beginning with the treatment of Greece as
something between a pariah state and a sacrificial lamb, spark off a
never-ending feedback between economic instability and the authoritarianism
that feeds off it?
[1]
“Elections can change nothing” and “It is the MoU or nothing”, were typical of
the utterances that he greeted my first intervention at the Eurogroup with.
[2]
Moreover, if the Greek state had been barred from borrowing by Dr Schäuble’s
budget commissioner, Greek debt would still have piled up via the private banks
– as it did in Ireland and Spain.
Sinicisation (excerpt)
by Slavoj Žižek
http://www.lrb.co.uk/v37/n14/slavoj-zizek/sinicisation
[…]
An exemplary case of today’s
‘socialism’ is China, where the Communist Party is engaged in a campaign of
self-legitimisation which promotes three theses: 1) Communist Party rule alone
can guarantee successful capitalism; 2) the rule of the atheist Communist Party
alone can guarantee authentic religious freedom; and 3) continuing Communist
Party rule alone can guarantee that China will be a society of Confucian
conservative values (social harmony, patriotism, moral order). These aren’t
simply nonsensical paradoxes. The reasoning might go as follows: 1) without the
party’s stabilising power, capitalist development would explode into a chaos of
riots and protests; 2) religious factional struggles would disturb social
stability; and 3) unbridled hedonist individualism would corrode social
harmony. The third point is crucial, since what lies in the background is a
fear of the corrosive influence of Western ‘universal values’: freedom,
democracy, human rights and hedonist individualism. The ultimate enemy is not
capitalism as such but the rootless Western culture threatening China through
the free flow of the internet. It must be fought with Chinese patriotism; even
religion should be ‘sinicised’ to ensure social stability. A Communist Party
official in Xinjiang, Zhang Chunxian, said recently that while ‘hostile forces’
are stepping up their infiltration, religions must work under socialism to
serve economic development, social harmony, ethnic unity and the unification of
the country: ‘Only when one is a good citizen can one be a good believer.’
But this ‘sinicisation’ of
religion isn’t enough: any religion, no matter how ‘sinicised’, is incompatible
with membership of the Communist Party. An article in the newsletter of the
party’s Central Commission for Discipline Inspection claims that since it is a
‘founding ideological principle that Communist Party members cannot be
religious’, party members don’t enjoy the right to religious freedom: ‘Chinese
citizens have the freedom of religious belief, but Communist Party members are
not the same as regular citizens; they are fighters in the vanguard for a
communist consciousness.’ How does this exclusion of believers from the party
aid religious freedom? Marx’s analysis of the political imbroglio of the French
Revolution of 1848 comes to mind. The ruling Party of Order was the coalition
of the two royalist wings, the Bourbons and the Orleanists. The two parties
were, by definition, unable to find a common denominator in their royalism,
since one cannot be a royalist in general, only a supporter of a particular
royal house, so the only way for the two to unite was under the banner of the
‘anonymous kingdom of the Republic’. In other words, the only way to be a
royalist in general is to be a republican. The same is true of religion. One cannot
be religious in general: one can only believe in a particular god, or gods, to
the detriment of others. The failure of all attempts to unite religions shows
that the only way to be religious in general is under the banner of the
‘anonymous religion of atheism’. Effectively, only an atheist regime can
guarantee religious tolerance: the moment this atheist frame disappears,
factional struggle among different religions will explode. Although
fundamentalist Islamists all attack the godless West, the worst struggles go on
between them (IS focuses on killing Shia Muslims).
There is, however, a deeper
fear at work in the prohibition of religious belief for members of the
Communist Party. ‘It would have been best for the Chinese Communist Party if
its members were not to believe in anything, not even in communism,’ Zorana
Baković, the China correspondent for the Slovenian newspaper Delo, wrote
recently, ‘since numerous party members joined churches (most of them
Protestant churches) precisely because of their disappointment at how even the
smallest trace of their communist ideals had disappeared from today’s Chinese
politics.’
In short, the most serious
opposition to the Chinese party leadership today is presented by truly
convinced communists, a group composed of old, mostly retired party cadres who
feel betrayed by the unbridled capitalist corruption along with those
proletarians whom the ‘Chinese miracle’ has failed: farmers who have lost their
land, workers who have lost their jobs and wander around searching for a means
of survival, others who are exploited by companies like Foxconn etc. They often
take part in mass protests carrying placards bearing quotes from Mao. This
combination of experienced cadres and the poor who have nothing to lose is
potentially explosive. China is not a stable country with an authoritarian
regime that guarantees harmony and is thus able to keep capitalist dynamics
under control: every year thousands of rebellions of workers, farmers and
minorities have to be squashed by the authorities. No wonder official
propaganda talks incessantly of a harmonious society. This very insistence
bears witness to its opposite, the ever present threat of chaos and disorder.
One should apply the basic rule of Stalinist hermeneutics here: since the
official media do not openly report on the troubles, the most reliable way to
detect them is to search for the positive excesses in state propaganda – the
more harmony is celebrated, the more chaos and antagonism should be inferred.
China is full of antagonisms and barely controlled instabilities that
continually threaten to explode.
It is only against this
background that one can understand the religious politics of the Chinese Party:
the fear of belief is effectively the fear of communist ‘belief’, the fear of
those who remain faithful to the universal emancipatory message of communism.
One looks in vain at the ongoing ideological campaign for any mention of the
basic class antagonism made evident in the workers’ protests. There is no talk
of the threat of ‘proletarian communism’; all the fury is directed instead
against the foreign enemy. ‘Certain countries in the West,’ the party secretary
of the Chinese Academy of Social Sciences wrote in June 2014,
advertise their own values as
‘universal values’, and claim that their interpretations of freedom, democracy
and human rights are the standard by which all others must be measured. They
spare no expense when it comes to hawking their goods and peddling their wares
to every corner of the planet, and stir up ‘colour revolutions’ both before and
behind the curtain. Their goal is to infiltrate, break down and overthrow other
regimes. At home and abroad certain enemy forces make use of the term
‘universal values’ to smear the Chinese Communist Party, socialism with Chinese
characteristics, and China’s mainstream ideology. They scheme to use Western
value systems to change China, with the goal of letting Chinese people renounce
the Chinese Communist Party’s leadership and socialism with Chinese
characteristics, and allow China to once again become a colony of some
developed capitalist country.
Some of this is true, but the
particular truths cover over a more general lie. It is of course right that one
cannot and should not trust the Western powers’ promulgation of the ‘universal
values’ of freedom, democracy and human rights: that universality is false, and
conceals the West’s ideological biases. Even so, is it then enough to oppose
Western values with a particular alternative, such as the Confucianism that is
‘China’s mainstream ideology’?
Don’t we need a different universalism, a
different project of universal emancipation? The irony here is that ‘socialism
with Chinese characteristics’ effectively means socialism with capitalist
characteristics, i.e. a socialism that fully integrates China into the global
market. The universality of global capitalism is left intact, quietly accepted
as the only possible frame; the project of Confucian harmony is mobilised only
in order to keep a lid on the antagonisms that come along with global
capitalist dynamics. All that remains is a socialism with Confucian ‘national
colours’: a national socialism, whose social horizon is the patriotic promotion
of one’s own nation, while the antagonisms immanent in capitalist development
are projected onto a foreign enemy who poses a threat to social harmony. What
the Chinese party aims at in its patriotic propaganda, what it calls ‘socialism
with Chinese characteristics’, is yet another version of ‘alternative
modernity’: capitalism without class struggle.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)