by Dr. Stephanie Kelton,
Scott Fullwiler, Catherine Ruetschlin, Marshall Steinbaum
Executive Summary
More than 44 million Americans
are caught in a student debt trap. Collectively, they owe nearly $1.4 trillion
on outstanding student loan debt. Research shows that this level of debt hurts
the US economy in a variety of ways, holding back everything from small
business formation to new home buying, and even marriage and reproduction. It
is a problem that policymakers have attempted to mitigate with programs that
offer refinancing or partial debt cancellation. But what if something far more
ambitious were tried? What if the population were freed from making any future
payments on the current stock of outstanding student loan debt? Could it be
done, and if so, how? What would it mean for the US economy?
This report seeks to answer
those very questions. The analysis proceeds in three sections: the first
explores the current US context of increasing college costs and reliance on
debt to finance higher education; the second section works through the balance
sheet mechanics required to liberate Americans from student loan debt; and the
final section simulates the economic effects of this debt cancellation using
two models, Ray Fair’s US Macroeconomic Model (“the Fair model”) and Moody’s US
Macroeconomic Model.
Several important implications
emerge from this analysis. Student debt cancellation results in positive
macroeconomic feedback effects as average households’ net worth and disposable
income increase, driving new consumption and investment spending. In short, we
find that debt cancellation lifts GDP, decreases the average unemployment rate,
and results in little inflationary pressure (all over the 10-year horizon of
our simulations), while interest rates increase only modestly. Though the
federal budget deficit does increase, state-level budget positions improve as a
result of the stronger economy. The use of two models with contrasting long-run
theoretical foundations offers a plausible range for each of these effects and
demonstrates the robustness of our results.
A one-time policy of student debt
cancellation, in which the federal government cancels the loans it holds
directly and takes over the financing of privately owned loans on behalf of
borrowers, results in the following macroeconomic effects (all dollar values
are in real, inflation-adjusted terms, using 2016 as the base year):
The policy of debt
cancellation could boost real GDP by an average of $86 billion to $108 billion
per year. Over the 10-year forecast, the policy generates between $861 billion and
$1,083 billion in real GDP (2016 dollars).
Eliminating student debt
reduces the average unemployment rate by 0.22 to 0.36 percentage points over
the 10-year forecast.
Peak job creation in the first
few years following the elimination of student loan debt adds roughly 1.2
million to 1.5 million new jobs per year.
The inflationary effects of
cancelling the debt are macroeconomically insignificant. In the Fair model
simulations, additional inflation peaks at about 0.3 percentage points and
turns negative in later years. In the Moody’s model, the effect is even
smaller, with the pickup in inflation peaking at a trivial 0.09 percentage
points.
Nominal interest rates rise
modestly. In the early years, the Federal Reserve raises target rates 0.3 to
0.5 percentage points; in later years, the increase falls to just 0.2
percentage points. The effect on nominal longer-term interest rates peaks at
0.25 to 0.5 percentage points and declines thereafter, settling at 0.21 to 0.35
percentage points.
The net budgetary effect for
the federal government is modest, with a likely increase in the deficit-to-GDP
ratio of 0.65 to 0.75 percentage points per year. Depending on the federal
government’s budget position overall, the deficit ratio could rise more
modestly, ranging between 0.59 and 0.61 percentage points. However, given that
the costs of funding the Department of Education’s student loans have already
been incurred (discussed in detail in Section 2), the more relevant estimates
for the impacts on the government’s budget position relative to current levels
are an annual increase in the deficit ratio of between 0.29 and 0.37 percentage
points. (This is explained in further detail in Appendix B.)
State budget deficits as a
percentage of GDP improve by about 0.11 percentage points during the entire
simulation period.
Research suggests many other
positive spillover effects that are not accounted for in these simulations,
including increases in small business formation, degree attainment, and
household formation, as well as improved access to credit and reduced household
vulnerability to business cycle downturns. Thus, our results provide a
conservative estimate of the macro effects of student debt liberation.
To read the full report
click here.
No comments:
Post a Comment